Traditionally,
cornucopians do not worry about protecting resources because they believe that
humans will be able to develop technology in response to scarcity. Although
this has appeared to be the case in history, Homer-Dixon criticizes the
cornucopian theory by claiming that its purported trend may not continue to be
the reality in the future. In Homer-Dixon’s discussion of the shortcomings of
cornucopians’ theories, he cites seven reasons that human ingenuity will not be
able to overcome scarcity. His seventh and final reason that cornucopians’
predictions will not come to fruition is that future environmental problems
will reduce the supply of ingenuity available in a society. He elaborates on
this point by explaining that environmental problems will create complex legal
issues and social friction, thereby decreasing the ability of policymakers to
be good “social engineers.” Homer-Dixon’s explanation of this point is underdeveloped,
however, because the term “supply of ingenuity” can be much more expansive. To
develop on Homer-Dixon’s reasoning, I also argue that the decrease in supply of
ingenuity relates to two factors: decreases in investment in research and
development for solutions to environmental problems, and more attention to
national security issues raised by environmental problems. Then, I will explain
how these reasons account for the likelihood that scarcity will be the most
prominent cause conflict in the future.
First, as scarcity
increases, the amount of money, labor and capital invested in research and
development for environmental problems will necessarily decrease, which in turn
reduces the supply of ingenuity. More money will be spent addressing the social
inequalities caused by scarcity instead of developing solutions to prevent
resource scarcity in the first place. During a water shortage crisis, more
money would be spent on addressing the immediate water needs of the country’s
citizens by providing bottled water than would be allocated on research and
development for long-term water purification systems, for example. This
redistribution of funding therefore limits the supply of ingenuity to resolve scarcity issues. Similarly, labor and capital resources will be selectively used to
address pressing scarcity issues instead of researching enduring technological
solutions. If not enough money, labor and capital are invested to encourage
human ingenuity in solving environmental problems, Homer-Dixon will be correct
in his argument that cornucopians mistakenly rely on technology development to
resolve scarcity.
Homer-Dixon also
explains that domestic social friction will reduce the supply of ingenuity, but
I argue that it is more complex; national security problems will also affect nations’
abilities to be effective social engineers. As we’ve discussed in class,
scarcity and environmental issues can threaten national security because they
can disrupt the function of a state and the wellbeing of its citizens. In the
face of environmental problems, governments will have to prioritize their
agendas and choose between social welfare of their citizens, technological development and national
security of the state. If a government prioritizes national security over
technological development, more effort will be spent on developing effective international
policies and defense strategies than on technologies to counteract negative threats of scarcity. As
a result, supply of ingenuity toward domestic policy and technological
innovation to resolve scarcity problems will diminish. Once again, as supply of
ingenuity decreases, humans will be less likely to engineer a solution to
scarcity.
Through
my expansion of Homer-Dixon’s explanation, it is now even more convincing that
humans will most likely not be able to develop technology to override scarcity
problems. His seven factors culminate to the conclusion that because humans
cannot avoid scarcity, the scarcity of renewable resources will be a cause of
significant domestic and interstate conflict. Although some scholars advocate for
the resource curse theory, and some believe instead that a combination of
abundance of nonrenewable resources and scarcity of renewable resources is most
likely to lead to states of conflict, I take a different approach. I believe
that in the future the likely cause of conflict will be scarcity, not abundance.
Eventually, overuse and exploitation of natural resources will cause
nonrenewable resources to become scarce even in formerly abundant areas. As Homer-Dixon explained, human technology will not be able to preserve abundance of any resource. Furthermore, environmental degradation of seemingly renewable resources will
cause further strains on supplies. As a result, there will be civil and
international conflicts over the distribution of scarce nonrenewable and
renewable resources, particularly in developing nations with weak political
institutions. This scarcity of resources will be further exacerbated by rapid
population growth.
Homer-Dixon's arguments that humans ingenuity cannot tackle scarcity problems are weakly stated, but overall accurate. Furthermore, his arguments lead us to the conclusion that scarcity of resources will be the most probable cause of conflict in the future.
Catherine,
ReplyDeleteInteresting thoughts. At the end of your piece, you mention that in the future, there will be civil and international conflicts over the distribution of resources, specifically in developing nations with weak political institutions. In my post, I mentioned the importance of taking into account institutions in determining prospects for conflicts amid an abundance of a resource. Since you argue that resource scarcity will play a large role in conflict, do you think that institution type would have a significant effect in alleviating the "decrease in supply of ingenuity", which would help deal with scarcity? If so how, and if not, what other factors would you take into account?
Catherine,
ReplyDeleteI think that by extending the definition of what Homer-Dixon considers "supply of ingenuity" within a state, you make the overall argument much more appealing. Whereas Homer-Dixon oversimplified the constraints that resource scarcity might place on a state, you enumerated them in a much more realistic fashion. Good job with addressing the key issues in this post. However, towards the end of the post you describe your primary concern for international welfare as the degree of scarcity that we face, not abundance, but do you think that it is possible that local pockets of resource abundance in a global setting of scarcity could be cause for conflict as well?